The best way to
steal
wear a suit & tie
USE A PEN
And have Congress write you up
special interest legislation
Defending this tax break are highly paid lobbyists such as Douglas Lowenstein and Grover Norquist
They're Getting
Richer!
Time Magazine By Daniel Kadlec: AUG. 12, 2003
The ink was still wet on president Bush's stock-dividend tax-rate cut in
early June when Corus Bankshares in Chicago voted to triple its annual payout.
CEO Robert Glickman said the move was "solely in reaction" to the new tax
treatment and that he was "very pleased" to provide shareholders with a beefy
new payment. Little wonder. The Glickman family owns half the company, and his
25% stake in the bank will generate $5.8 million in annual after-tax income, up
from $1.3 million.
Glickman isn't the only executive who will reap a windfall thanks to the
Bush cut, which lowered the tax rate on dividends to 15% from a top marginal
rate of 38.6%. Since May more than 200 firms have raised their payouts to
shareholders, and — in a time of scrutiny over pay packages — the increases are
minting riches for bosses who own a lot of company stock. Banking giant
Citigroup, for example, just raised its annual dividend 75% to $1.40--very
timely for CEO Sandy Weill, who is retiring from that role at the end of the
year but is staying on as chairman. With a net worth of $1 billion, it's not as
if Weill needs the money. Still, his 22 million Citi shares will spin off $27
million a year in after-tax income, up from $11 million. "That income stream
only comes because I've taken the risk along with the other shareholders in this
company," Weill told Time.
He's right, of course. There's nothing illegal here, nor is there
anything to suggest that Bush had corporate chiefs and not economic stimulus in
mind when the bill was passed. Shareholder groups applaud bigger dividends.
Unlike stock options, restricted shares, annual bonuses, forgivable loans and
free trips on company yachts and jets for executives, dividends directly benefit
all who own the stock. Still, a controlling family like the Glickmans will enjoy
an income boost without having to sell a single share and dilute their control.
The family's prodigious raise was "part of the equation" when the
dividend-increase decision was made, concedes Tim Taylor, chief financial
officer at Corus. "But so was the fact that a lot of our shareholders had been
telling us we have too much capital and they'd like some of it returned to
them."
Wall Street moneymen have been among the most aggressive in raising dividends:
Goldman Sachs, where executives and directors collectively own 25 million
company shares, doubled its annual payout to $1 a share. After tax, CEO Henry
Paulson's 4 million shares will spin off $3.4 million in dividends — up from
$1.2 million. Goldman spokesman Peter Rose says it's "preposterous" that the
move had anything to do with personal enrichment and that Goldman's dividend was
merely brought up to the industry average. Bear Stearns, long famous for
nosebleed executive pay, raised its dividend 18%, to 80 cents a share. After
tax, CEO James Cayne's 4.8 million shares will pay $3.3 million in dividends
each year, up from $1.8 million. Through a spokesman, Cayne declined to comment.
The
mother of all dividend pay raises emerged at Microsoft, where co-founder Bill
Gates will enjoy an after-tax windfall of $82 million a year thanks to the
company's newly created 8 cent-a-share dividend. Like Weill, Gates doesn't need
the income. He is already the richest person in the world, with $30 billion in
Microsoft stock. But the sheer size of his dividend is eye popping. Another
company that has long avoided dividends is Viacom. But in July it said it would
start paying 24 cents a share annually, which would give CEO Sumner Redstone an
annual after-tax haul of $41 million. A Viacom spokesman says the dividend is a
smart way to share the company's cash flow with
stockholders.
These hefty pay bumps from dividends may make executives look greedy at a
time when their image is bruised. "But it's what you want," says Charles Elson,
director of the Weinberg Center for Corporate Governance. "It returns capital to
investors, who are better than companies at redeploying it." And smart investors
are figuring out how to take advantage. Tobias Levkovich, a strategist at Smith
Barney, is hunting for companies with families or managements that have a large
stake, figuring that the dividend will be raised and boost the stock. "We think
that's a good starting point," says Levkovich, whose screen includes retailers
Dillard's and Best Buy along with homebuilder Lennar. Dividends are a clean way
for many CEOs to give themselves a big raise — and you have to figure that they
will.
Tax breaks for
billionaires:
Loophole for hedge fund managers
costs
billions in tax revenue
Randall Dodd
July 24,
2007
This policy
memo focuses on the privileged tax treatment given to hedge fund managers that
results in a conservative estimate of over $6 billion in forgone tax
revenue.
Private
investment companies, organized as hedge funds or private equity firms, have
recently grown into major economic forces in the U.S. economy. They mobilize
capital, and often leverage it with borrowed funds, in order to accumulate a
tremendous amount of assets under their management. These investments include
leveraged buyouts; market-neutral investment strategies in publicly traded
stocks and bonds, energy, and other commodities; various arbitrage strategies;
as well as many lesser known and some entirely unreported transactions. Hedge
funds are big players in the large corporate take-over activity that reached
$3.6 trillion in 2006¸ and they are also responsible for a significant share of
trading volume on the major stock exchanges and in some over-the-counter
derivatives markets.
These private
pools of capital are unregulated, or exempt from Securities and Exchange
Commission (SEC) regulation, under both the Investment Advisors Act and the
Investment Company Act. While these exemptions were once justified on the
grounds that such investment firms were small, closely held, and did not raise
their capital in public capital markets, the exemptions are no longer consistent
with today’s reality. Today these firms are huge, have a wide number and range
of investors, and the Internet has blurred the distinction between public and
private marketing.
In addition
to being unregulated, these financial institutions also reap substantial
benefits from special tax provisions that, like the regulatory framework, are no
longer appropriate. The professional fund managers of these hedge funds and
private equity firms are allowed to treat a substantial portion of their
compensation as capital gains, meaning they are most likely taxed at 15% rather
than the 35% rate that applies to ordinary income such as wages and salary. Such
an exemption, however, makes little sense: in economic terms, the fund managers
(also known as investment advisors) perform a professional service, much like
lawyers or doctors, and receive remuneration for their
labor.
These
investment advisors and hedge fund managers can take advantage of this tax
structure because they are often compensated through a scheme that, in part,
pays them according to the returns on the fund. The industry standard for hedge
fund managers is “two and twenty,” which is shorthand for an “overhead” fee of
2% of capital under management plus carried interest (often called a “carry”) of
20% of the returns on the fund. Thus a $100 million fund earning 20% would pay
its fund manager $2 million for overhead and $4 million in carry. The carry
portion of their compensation is treated under the tax code as capital gains for
the fund manager and is taxable at the much lower capital gains tax rate of
15%.
This policy
memo focuses on this special tax break, explaining why it is not economically
sound and offering reasonable estimates of what it costs the U.S. Treasury and
ultimately other tax payers in terms of lost tax revenue.
Tax
treatment distorts economic incentives
There are
two things economically wrong with this special tax provision for hedge fund
managers. First is its impact on economic efficiency. It creates
inconsistent economic incentives (i.e., distortions) for some labor income to be
treated as ordinary income while other labor income is treated as capital gains,
and the work done by investment advisors is undeniably a professional, laboring
activity.1 Fund managers at pension funds, trusts, and endowments who provide
similar professional services are paid a salary and possibly a bonus, and these
are all treated as ordinary income. Only because hedge funds and private equity
firms are organized as limited liability partnerships—which are already treated
favorably for tax and liability purposes—are these same professional services
taxed differently. The result is a distortion in the compensation and after-tax
income between these super rich hedge fund managers and millions of others in
the workforce.
The
second thing wrong with this exemption is that these super rich fund managers do
not need and certainly do not deserve special tax breaks. Alpha Magazine
reports the compensation for hedge fund managers each year. The top earner for
2006 received $1.7 billion, the second highest received $1.4 billion, and the
third $1.3 billion. That adds to $4.4 billion for three people. The top 25 hedge
managers received, on average, $570 million for a total of $14.25
billion.
|
Compensation |
Tax Treatment
---------------------- |
Benefit |
|
|
|
Capital
Gains |
Ordinary
Income |
|
Average of Top
25 |
$570,000,000 |
$59,850,000 |
$139,650,000 |
$79,800,000 |
|
|
|
|
|
Total |
$14,250,000,000 |
$1,496,250,000 |
$3,491,250,000 |
$1,995,000,000 |
Not only
do these rich individuals have no need of tax breaks, the hedge fund and private
equity industries have demonstrated time and again that they are not exemplary
economic citizens who deserve privileged tax treatment. While most fund managers
are probably law-abiding investment advisors, there are innumerable examples of
wrong doing. The major types of failures and illegal activities include insider
trading, IPO manipulation, embezzlement, and defrauding mutual fund
investors.2
Defending
this tax break are highly paid lobbyists such as Douglas Lowenstein and Grover
Norquist who loudly and repeatedly make the claim that taxing hedge fund
managers like everyone else will harm the average working family. They claim
that taxing hedge funds like normal income will harm pension fund returns. This
is wrong on two levels. First, the tax change would apply to hedge fund managers
and not investors (many pension funds invest in hedge funds). Second, pension
funds do not pay taxes. These lobbyists also claim that it would increase the
cost of consumer goods and services because so many stores and chain restaurants
are owned by private equity firms and hedge funds. This, too, is preposterous
because, again, the tax does not apply to the investors or owners of those
businesses but only the investment advisors who manage the funds of those
investors. Moreover, the businesses owned by private pools of capital will have
to compete with other similar businesses providing consumer goods and
services—only now on a level playing field—and they will not be able to
arbitrarily raise their prices.
The
revenue costs
How much
revenue does this loophole cost the federal government? The following analysis
creates a reasonable estimate using what information is available from the
unregulated, non-transparent hedge fund industry.
The data come
from market research firms Greenwich Associates and HedgeFund.net. These firms
study the industry in order to help investors become more informed about the
size, returns, and range of opportunities available in the area of
professionally managed private capital pools. The size of the hedge fund
industry is best measured by the amount of capital invested in these funds.
HedgeFund.net estimates what is called “assets under advisement” to be $2.4
trillion for 2006. Greenwich Associates regularly reports on its survey of a
large number of fund managers, and the results for the past three years show
that hedge fund investments’ across-the board-investment strategies returned
10.5% to investors after fees. This implies that returns were 13.1% before fees,
and if investment managers received the industry standard 20%, then their
remuneration treated as “carry” was $63 billion for 2006 (20% of returns
calculated as rate of return times capital of $2.4
trillion).
Of course not
all hedge funds are located in the United States, but estimates are that 70% of
hedge funds measured by capital invested are based domestically.3 The funds may
also have subsidiaries in the Cayman Islands for certain other tax purposes, but
the fund managers are taxed based on where they live, and most live in the
United States. If we take a more conservative estimate that 50% of hedge fund
assets under advisement are managed by advisors located in the United States,
then half of those investment advisory earnings are taxable under U.S. law. At
the current 15% capital gains tax rate, the taxable amount would result in $4.75
billion in tax payments; at the top rate (35%) on ordinary income, it would sum
to $11.05 billion. The loss to the U.S. Treasury, therefore, amounts to at least
$6.3 billion a year.
In addition to these aggregate
numbers, there are a few specific figures coming out of the private capital
market worth considering. Alpha Magazine’s figures for the top hedge fund
managers and its estimates of the break out of compensation between salary and
bonus can be used to further estimate the revenue implication by applying that
break out to the portion of total compensation that is likely treated as capital
gains. The different tax rates then can be used to calculate how much these
three individuals benefit from this quirk in the tax law.
A simple
calculation shows that this preferential tax treatment for the top 25
individuals alone costs the Treasury almost $2 billion.4 It serves to suggest
that our estimates of tax losses are indeed conservative, as the losses from
these 25 managers alone amounts to almost a third of our
total.
Conclusion
Congress has
the opportunity to correct a bad economic policy and free up resources to fund
better priorities. This analysis points to the need to update the nation’s tax
laws dealing with private pools of capital. The current law is generating
inefficiencies and great inequality by granting tax breaks to individuals who do
not need and do not deserve such favors. The nation has greater and more
deserving priorities. If the amount of tax revenue lost to private equity firm
managers is equivalent to that lost with hedge funds, then the combined amount
would be $12.6 billion. This forgone revenue stream could, for example, fully
fund the five-year, $35 billion expansion of SCHIP, the public health insurance
program for low-income children.
Notes
1. While investment
advisors often invest their own capital in the funds they manage, this tax issue
concerns the returns on their labor and not their capital.
2. As for insider trading,
the SEC is investigating numerous cases of hedge funds exploiting insider
information about merger and acquisition announcements to trade ahead in the
credit derivatives markets. In terms of IPO manipulation, Deutsche Bank and
several hedge funds were recently prosecuted in France for manipulating an IPO
of a telecom firm. Dozens of hedge funds have also been found to have ripped off
mutual fund investors by late trading and market timing a large number of mutual
funds. This problem was brought to light by Eliot Spitzer’s investigation into
Canary Capital Hedge Fund and Bank of America. For recent examples of
embezzlement look to the cases involving Bayou Capital, IPOF Fund, and Wood
River. In addition there have been some colossal failures, including: Long Term
Capital Management (interest rates), Amaranth and Mother Rock (energy), Red Kite
(copper), and Bear Sterns’ hedge funds (subprime debt).
3. Alpha Magazine
reports that 77 of the largest 100 hedge funds are located in the U.S., and that
the 100 largest hedge funds manage 70% of the total capital invested in hedge
funds.
4. The calculation is based
on Alpha Magazine figures for average compensation breakdown between salary and
bonus, which is 70% bonus, and assumes the bonus was treated as capital gains.
Thus 70% of compensation is taxed at 15% capital gains rate and benefit is the
difference between that and 35%. If entire compensation were taxed at capital
gains rate, then the benefit would be 43% higher.
Hedge funds sweeping through
beleaguered
ethanol industry for
bargains
By
Anthony
Effinger and Katherine
Burton
Bloomberg
News
A
mile down an unpaved road on the outskirts of Canton, Ill., population 14,500,
stands a shuttered ethanol plant.
Corn farmers
in the area chipped in $5,000 to $300,000 each — some even mortgaged their farms
— to form the Central Illinois Energy Cooperative. They broke ground on the
refinery in 2006, hoping that ethanol would bring higher prices for their corn
and more jobs for Canton. The town had been in trouble since 1983, when
International Harvester closed its plow factory there.
The ethanol
plant was a poor replacement. Central Illinois Energy (CIE), the corporation
that built the plant, went bankrupt in December 2007 without having produced a
drop of fuel, hurt by construction delays and $40 million in cost overruns. The
260 farmers in the co-op lost every dime.
Some of them
blame the flameout on Andy Redleaf, whose Minneapolis- based hedge fund firm,
Whitebox Advisors controls the plant.
With $2.7
billion in assets, Whitebox is one of a small group of bottom-fishing hedge
funds sifting through the wreckage of a highflying ethanol industry that started
falling to earth on June 20, 2006.
That day, the
price of ethanol peaked at $4.23 a gallon on the Chicago Board of Trade, buoyed
by a strong economy and former President George W. Bush's pledge to replace 75
percent of the oil the U.S. imports from the Middle East with ethanol by
2025.
Distillers
erected dozens of the plants across the Great Plains, backed by some very smart
money. Microsoft co- founder Bill Gates invested $84 million in Pacific Ethanol,
based in Sacramento, Calif. Hedge-fund managers David Einhorn and Daniel Loeb
backed Denver-based BioFuel Energy Corp.
Then the
financial crisis hit. Demand waned, and supply surged. BioFuel has made money in
just two quarters since going public in June 2007. By December 2008, the price
of ethanol had collapsed to $1.40 a gallon. Pacific Ethanol's plants went
bankrupt.
"There was
too much built too quickly, with too much leverage," says Neil Koehler, the
company's chief executive.
Great Plains
vulture
Whitebox's
involvement in the Canton ethanol plant started when it bought a fraction of an
$87.5 million syndicated loan that Credit Suisse Group arranged for the farmers'
cooperative in April 2006.
It was part
of a bigger ethanol play. Redleaf also bought $28.4 million of bonds issued by
Pekin, Ill.-based Aventine Renewable Energy Holdings when it emerged from
bankruptcy in March, a right he had as a holder of Aventine's original
debt.
And he owned
bonds issued by bankrupt Sioux Falls, S.D.-based VeraSun Energy Corp., which
raised $420 million in a 2006 public offering and operated 16 ethanol plants in
eight states before it went under.
Redleaf isn't
normally an energy investor. The core of his hedging strategy is
capital-structure arbitrage, in which he looks for bonds that pay fat interest
rates, then hedges the risk of those bonds by making a separate wager that the
issuing company's stock will fall, called a short sale.
If the bonds
tumble, the stock probably will, too, and the arbitrageur makes enough money on
the short sale to cover the bond loss — and still collects the
interest.
Unlike
Redleaf, the cooperative didn't have any shares to short. When the bonds
crashed, Redleaf could have taken the loss and moved on. Instead, he took
control of the plant in bankruptcy.
That's a
source of bitterness in Canton. Before the co-op went bust, the farmers sought a
new loan from Whitebox.
"Whitebox
proposed a bridge loan, which was not workable because of onerous terms," says
Jay Sutor, a farmer-investor.
The interest
rate on the loan was about 20 percent, and Whitebox, already a small holder of
the plant's equity, was to get 25 percent more as a fee, Sutor says. The farmers
balked.
Whitebox also
used its equity ownership to block the sale of the plant to other buyers, which
could have salvaged some of the farmers' investment, says Dennis Streitmatter,
an investor and co-op board member.
"It took a
100 percent vote to do anything," Streitmatter says. "And they always voted
against it."
Whitebox
Chief Operating Officer Jonathan Wood says he knows of no offers to buy the CIE
before it went bankrupt.
Redleaf says
Whitebox spent $30 million to finish the plant — much more than the farmers
invested — and made a sincere effort to save it.
Going
private
CIE was one
of several private companies that Whitebox invested in over the past few years,
a common occurrence among hedge funds in the boom years as they drifted away
from publicly traded stocks and bonds in a search for higher
returns.
Whitebox has
sold several private-equity investments to return money to investors who
redeemed their Whitebox stake after the 2008 crash. In April, the firm agreed to
sell a dozen grain elevators to Toronto-based Ceres Global Ag for $74 million in
cash and stock. Whitebox made money on the sale, Wood
says.
Even so,
Redleaf says he's done with running private companies.
"We prefer
shuffling paper to making widgets," he says in his office overlooking
Minneapolis's Lake Calhoun.
His desk is
covered with newspapers, and atop the stack rests a magnifying glass that
Redleaf, who suffers from macular degeneration — a disease that causes a
progressive blurring of vision — uses to read.
That problem
aside, Redleaf sometimes makes his short commute to work on a Segway
scooter.
Redleaf says
he has put the Canton plant up for sale and will avoid private-equity deals in
the future.
Redleaf
hasn't escaped Canton yet. The Illinois Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) in
March asked the state attorney general to force CIE and a nearby grain-handling
facility to clean up a discharge of black sludge that killed turtles in a nearby
pond.
The closed
plant contains 2.3 million gallons of toxic soup from the ethanol-making
process, says Canton City Attorney Chrissie Peterson. The city has plugged a
pipe leading from the plant to make sure none of the material makes its way into
the town's water-treatment facility.
Wood says
Whitebox is cooperating with the Illinois EPA.
"There were
high hopes for the ethanol plant," Peterson says. "It has left a bitter
taste."
Getting into
ethanol
A Minneapolis
native, Redleaf has been interested in the markets since he was a child. At 11,
he started reading copies of Forbes and Value Line that his father, an
options-trading doctor, brought home.
The ethanol
cooperative Redleaf invested in was the dream of Mike Smith, an executive at
MidAmerica National Bank in Canton. Smith convinced 260 farmers and about 100
other investors to pony up $4 million to form the co-op, according to farmers
who invested. About 70 signed letters of credit for another $5
million.
Smith didn't
return telephone calls.
The $4
million was barely enough for a down payment on the 37-million-gallon-per-year
ethanol plant. The farmers went to Zurich-based Credit Suisse, which offered its
$87.5 million syndicated loan.
Canton
officials were eager to help, too. The town sold $26 million in bonds to upgrade
its water system, partly to supply the 200 million gallons of water the plant
would need each year.
Math is what
attracted Redleaf to ethanol, he says. The price of corn determines much of its
cost, while the price of gasoline, with which it is blended, helps determine the
ethanol price.
"It's a
series of complex options on inputs and outputs," Redleaf
says.
The
investment became more interesting in 2007, when ethanol prices plunged and the
Canton plant suffered construction delays. The Credit Suisse debt dropped to
just pennies on the dollar. Whitebox bought more.
The Whitebox
portfolio manager handling the investment, Nick Swenson, had experience
analyzing distressed assets at Varde Partners, another Minneapolis
fund.
Swenson, who
left Whitebox in February 2009 to found his own firm, declined to
comment.
After the
co-op had run through the cash provided by the Credit Suisse loan, Smith went to
Whitebox looking for more money. Swenson assured co-op members that Whitebox
would help, the farmers say.
"There were
several times when they would offer to give us some money, and it wouldn't come
through," says CIE board member and farmer Tim Wagenbach, who says he put up
$63,000, including $48,000 via a letter of credit, and lost it all. "They wanted
to own the company."
Redleaf says
he never expected to own the plant.
In November
2007, with weeks to go before the plant had to make a payment to Credit Suisse,
Swenson offered a $15 million bridge loan at 20 percent, the farmers say. They
rejected the terms, and CIE declared bankruptcy in Illinois federal court on
Dec. 13, 2007. Whitebox Chief Legal Officer Mark Strefling says he doesn't know
the terms of any proposed bridge loan.
A group of
creditors led by Whitebox won permission from the bankruptcy judge to take over
the ethanol plant on April 24, 2008. The creditors held $80 million in CIE debt,
80 percent of it owned by Whitebox.
Whitebox
renamed the facility Riverland BioFuels, finished construction and, in late
2008, fired it up. It halted production in March after a new slide in ethanol's
price, to $1.53 a gallon on March 25 from $2.14 on Nov. 30, 2009. A Whitebox
executive came to town and fired 31 of the 41 workers.
Stock rally
As of June 1,
Aventine shares traded at $37.50 on the over-the-counter market. Houlihan Lokey,
the Los Angeles-based investment bank that valued Aventine in bankruptcy,
estimated that the new shares would be worth just $25.
The shares
rose after Aventine reported to the bankruptcy court that its business had
improved. The company had net income of $27 million in the second half of 2009,
according to a regulatory filing.
"They've been
making money like crazy," says Michael Welsh, who has been climbing around
Aventine's Pekin plant for 16 years as a consulting
engineer.
Whitebox COO
Wood agrees Aventine is profitable. "It's a very good trade," he
says.
The old
shareholders, wiped out in the bankruptcy, are incensed. Welsh, who says he
bought 430,000 Aventine shares before it went bankrupt, says the hedge funds
forced the bankruptcy filing in order to take control.
Redleaf
responds that his actions in Aventine were proper.
The
still-unanswered question for Whitebox is whether the firm can make enough on
its Aventine shares to cover potential losses on CIE.
For
Richer
I. The Disappearing Middle
When I was a
teenager growing up on Long Island, one of my favorite excursions was a trip to
see the great Gilded Age mansions of the North Shore. Those mansions weren't
just pieces of architectural history. They were monuments to a bygone social
era, one in which the rich could afford the armies of servants needed to
maintain a house the size of a European palace. By the time I saw them, of
course, that era was long past. Almost none of the Long Island mansions were
still private residences. Those that hadn't been turned into museums were
occupied by nursing homes or private schools.
For the America I
grew up in -- the America of the 1950's and 1960's -- was a middle-class
society, both in reality and in feel. The vast income and wealth inequalities of
the Gilded Age had disappeared. Yes, of course, there was the poverty of the
underclass -- but the conventional wisdom of the time viewed that as a social
rather than an economic problem. Yes, of course, some wealthy businessmen and
heirs to large fortunes lived far better than the average American. But they
weren't rich the way the robber barons who built the mansions had been rich, and
there weren't that many of them. The days when plutocrats were a force to be
reckoned with in American society, economically or politically, seemed long
past.
Daily experience
confirmed the sense of a fairly equal society. The economic disparities you were
conscious of were quite muted. Highly educated professionals -- middle managers,
college teachers, even lawyers -- often claimed that they earned less than
unionized blue-collar workers. Those considered very well off lived in
split-levels, had a housecleaner come in once a week and took summer vacations
in Europe. But they sent their kids to public schools and drove themselves to
work, just like everyone else.
But that was long
ago. The middle-class America of my youth was another country.
We are now living
in a new Gilded Age, as extravagant as the original. Mansions have made a
comeback. Back in 1999 this magazine profiled Thierry Despont, the ''eminence of
excess,'' an architect who specializes in designing houses for the superrich.
His creations typically range from 20,000 to 60,000 square feet; houses at the
upper end of his range are not much smaller than the White House. Needless to
say, the armies of servants are back, too. So are the yachts. Still, even J.P.
Morgan didn't have a Gulfstream.
As the story
about Despont suggests, it's not fair to say that the fact of widening
inequality in America has gone unreported. Yet glimpses of the lifestyles of the
rich and tasteless don't necessarily add up in people's minds to a clear picture
of the tectonic shifts that have taken place in the distribution of income and
wealth in this country. My sense is that few people are aware of just how much
the gap between the very rich and the rest has widened over a relatively short
period of time. In fact, even bringing up the subject exposes you to charges of
''class warfare,'' the ''politics of envy'' and so on. And very few people
indeed are willing to talk about the profound effects -- economic, social and
political -- of that widening gap.
Yet you can't
understand what's happening in America today without understanding the extent,
causes and consequences of the vast increase in inequality that has taken place
over the last three decades, and in particular the astonishing concentration of
income and wealth in just a few hands. To make sense of the current wave of
corporate scandal, you need to understand how the man in the gray flannel suit
has been replaced by the imperial C.E.O. The concentration of income at the top
is a key reason that the United States, for all its economic achievements, has
more poverty and lower life expectancy than any other major advanced nation.
Above all, the growing concentration of wealth has reshaped our political
system: it is at the root both of a general shift to the right and of an extreme
polarization of our politics.
But before we get
to all that, let's take a look at who gets what.
II. The New Gilded Age
The Securities
and Exchange Commission hath no fury like a woman scorned. The messy divorce
proceedings of Jack Welch, the legendary former C.E.O. of General Electric, have
had one unintended benefit: they have given us a peek at the perks of the
corporate elite, which are normally hidden from public view. For it turns out
that when Welch retired, he was granted for life the use of a Manhattan
apartment (including food, wine and laundry), access to corporate jets and a
variety of other in-kind benefits, worth at least $2 million a year. The perks
were revealing: they illustrated the extent to which corporate leaders now
expect to be treated like ancien regime royalty. In monetary terms, however, the
perks must have meant little to Welch. In 2000, his last full year running G.E.,
Welch was paid $123 million, mainly in stock and stock options.
Is it news that
C.E.O.'s of large American corporations make a lot of money? Actually, it is.
They were always well paid compared with the average worker, but there is simply
no comparison between what executives got a generation ago and what they are
paid today.
Over the past 30
years most people have seen only modest salary increases: the average annual
salary in America, expressed in 1998 dollars (that is, adjusted for inflation),
rose from $32,522 in 1970 to $35,864 in 1999. That's about a 10 percent increase
over 29 years -- progress, but not much. Over the same period, however,
according to Fortune magazine, the average real annual compensation of the top
100 C.E.O.'s went from $1.3 million -- 39 times the pay of an average worker --
to $37.5 million, more than 1,000 times the pay of ordinary workers.
The explosion in
C.E.O. pay over the past 30 years is an amazing story in its own right, and an
important one. But it is only the most spectacular indicator of a broader story,
the reconcentration of income and wealth in the U.S. The rich have always been
different from you and me, but they are far more different now than they were
not long ago -- indeed, they are as different now as they were when F. Scott
Fitzgerald made his famous remark.
That's a
controversial statement, though it shouldn't be. For at least the past 15 years
it has been hard to deny the evidence for growing inequality in the United
States. Census data clearly show a rising share of income going to the top 20
percent of families, and within that top 20 percent to the top 5 percent, with a
declining share going to families in the middle. Nonetheless, denial of that
evidence is a sizable, well-financed industry. Conservative think tanks have
produced scores of studies that try to discredit the data, the methodology and,
not least, the motives of those who report the obvious. Studies that appear to
refute claims of increasing inequality receive prominent endorsements on
editorial pages and are eagerly cited by right-leaning government officials.
Four years ago Alan Greenspan (why did anyone ever think that he was
nonpartisan?) gave a keynote speech at the Federal Reserve's annual Jackson Hole
conference that amounted to an attempt to deny that there has been any real
increase in inequality in America.
The concerted
effort to deny that inequality is increasing is itself a symptom of the growing
influence of our emerging plutocracy (more on this later). So is the fierce
defense of the backup position, that inequality doesn't matter -- or maybe even
that, to use Martha Stewart's signature phrase, it's a good thing. Meanwhile,
politically motivated smoke screens aside, the reality of increasing inequality
is not in doubt. In fact, the census data understate the case, because for
technical reasons those data tend to undercount very high incomes -- for
example, it's unlikely that they reflect the explosion in C.E.O. compensation.
And other evidence makes it clear not only that inequality is increasing but
that the action gets bigger the closer you get to the top. That is, it's not
simply that the top 20 percent of families have had bigger percentage gains than
families near the middle: the top 5 percent have done better than the next 15,
the top 1 percent better than the next 4, and so on up to Bill Gates.
Studies that try
to do a better job of tracking high incomes have found startling results. For
example, a recent study by the nonpartisan Congressional Budget Office used
income tax data and other sources to improve on the census estimates. The C.B.O.
study found that between 1979 and 1997, the after-tax incomes of the top 1
percent of families rose 157 percent, compared with only a 10 percent gain for
families near the middle of the income distribution. Even more startling results
come from a new study by Thomas Piketty, at the French research institute
Cepremap, and Emmanuel Saez, who is now at the University of California at
Berkeley. Using income tax data, Piketty and Saez have produced estimates of the
incomes of the well-to-do, the rich and the very rich back to 1913.
The first point
you learn from these new estimates is that the middle-class America of my youth
is best thought of not as the normal state of our society, but as an interregnum
between Gilded Ages. America before 1930 was a society in which a small number
of very rich people controlled a large share of the nation's wealth. We became a
middle-class society only after the concentration of income at the top dropped
sharply during the New Deal, and especially during World War II. The economic
historians Claudia Goldin and Robert Margo have dubbed the narrowing of income
gaps during those years the Great Compression. Incomes then stayed fairly
equally distributed until the 1970's: the rapid rise in incomes during the first
postwar generation was very evenly spread across the population.
Since the 1970's,
however, income gaps have been rapidly widening. Piketty and Saez confirm what I
suspected: by most measures we are, in fact, back to the days of ''The Great
Gatsby.'' After 30 years in which the income shares of the top 10 percent of
taxpayers, the top 1 percent and so on were far below their levels in the
1920's, all are very nearly back where they were.
And the big
winners are the very, very rich. One ploy often used to play down growing
inequality is to rely on rather coarse statistical breakdowns -- dividing the
population into five ''quintiles,'' each containing 20 percent of families, or
at most 10 ''deciles.'' Indeed, Greenspan's speech at Jackson Hole relied mainly
on decile data. From there it's a short step to denying that we're really
talking about the rich at all. For example, a conservative commentator might
concede, grudgingly, that there has been some increase in the share of national
income going to the top 10 percent of taxpayers, but then point out that anyone
with an income over $81,000 is in that top 10 percent. So we're just talking
about shifts within the middle class, right?
Wrong: the top 10
percent contains a lot of people whom we would still consider middle class, but
they weren't the big winners. Most of the gains in the share of the top 10
percent of taxpayers over the past 30 years were actually gains to the top 1
percent, rather than the next 9 percent. In 1998 the top 1 percent started at
$230,000. In turn, 60 percent of the gains of that top 1 percent went to the top
0.1 percent, those with incomes of more than $790,000. And almost half of those
gains went to a mere 13,000 taxpayers, the top 0.01 percent, who had an income
of at least $3.6 million and an average income of $17 million.
A stickler for
detail might point out that the Piketty-Saez estimates end in 1998 and that the
C.B.O. numbers end a year earlier. Have the trends shown in the data reversed?
Almost surely not. In fact, all indications are that the explosion of incomes at
the top continued through 2000. Since then the plunge in stock prices must have
put some crimp in high incomes -- but census data show inequality continuing to
increase in 2001, mainly because of the severe effects of the recession on the
working poor and near poor. When the recession ends, we can be sure that we will
find ourselves a society in which income inequality is even higher than it was
in the late 90's.
So claims that
we've entered a second Gilded Age aren't exaggerated. In America's middle-class
era, the mansion-building, yacht-owning classes had pretty much disappeared.
According to Piketty and Saez, in 1970 the top 0.01 percent of taxpayers had 0.7
percent of total income -- that is, they earned ''only'' 70 times as much as the
average, not enough to buy or maintain a mega-residence. But in 1998 the top
0.01 percent received more than 3 percent of all income. That meant that the
13,000 richest families in America had almost as much income as the 20 million
poorest households; those 13,000 families had incomes 300 times that of average
families.
And let me
repeat: this transformation has happened very quickly, and it is still going on.
You might think that 1987, the year Tom Wolfe published his novel ''The Bonfire
of the Vanities'' and Oliver Stone released his movie ''Wall Street,'' marked
the high tide of America's new money culture. But in 1987 the top 0.01 percent
earned only about 40 percent of what they do today, and top executives less than
a fifth as much. The America of ''Wall Street'' and ''The Bonfire of the
Vanities'' was positively egalitarian compared with the country we live in
today.
III. Undoing the New
Deal
In the middle of
the 1980's, as economists became aware that something important was happening to
the distribution of income in America, they formulated three main hypotheses
about its causes.
The
''globalization'' hypothesis tied America's changing income distribution to the
growth of world trade, and especially the growing imports of manufactured goods
from the third world. Its basic message was that blue-collar workers -- the sort
of people who in my youth often made as much money as college-educated middle
managers -- were losing ground in the face of competition from low-wage workers
in Asia. A result was stagnation or decline in the wages of ordinary people,
with a growing share of national income going to the highly educated.
A second
hypothesis, ''skill-biased technological change,'' situated the cause of growing
inequality not in foreign trade but in domestic innovation. The torrid pace of
progress in information technology, so the story went, had increased the demand
for the highly skilled and educated. And so the income distribution increasingly
favored brains rather than brawn.
Finally, the
''superstar'' hypothesis -- named by the Chicago economist Sherwin Rosen --
offered a variant on the technological story. It argued that modern technologies
of communication often turn competition into a tournament in which the winner is
richly rewarded, while the runners-up get far less. The classic example -- which
gives the theory its name -- is the entertainment business. As Rosen pointed
out, in bygone days there were hundreds of comedians making a modest living at
live shows in the borscht belt and other places. Now they are mostly gone; what
is left is a handful of superstar TV comedians.
The debates among
these hypotheses -- particularly the debate between those who attributed growing
inequality to globalization and those who attributed it to technology -- were
many and bitter. I was a participant in those debates myself. But I won't dwell
on them, because in the last few years there has been a growing sense among
economists that none of these hypotheses work.
I don't mean to
say that there was nothing to these stories. Yet as more evidence has
accumulated, each of the hypotheses has seemed increasingly inadequate.
Globalization can explain part of the relative decline in blue-collar wages, but
it can't explain the 2,500 percent rise in C.E.O. incomes. Technology may
explain why the salary premium associated with a college education has risen,
but it's hard to match up with the huge increase in inequality among the
college-educated, with little progress for many but gigantic gains at the top.
The superstar theory works for Jay Leno, but not for the thousands of people who
have become awesomely rich without going on TV.
The Great
Compression -- the substantial reduction in inequality during the New Deal and
the Second World War -- also seems hard to understand in terms of the usual
theories. During World War II Franklin Roosevelt used government control over
wages to compress wage gaps. But if the middle-class society that emerged from
the war was an artificial creation, why did it persist for another 30 years?
Some -- by no
means all -- economists trying to understand growing inequality have begun to
take seriously a hypothesis that would have been considered irredeemably
fuzzy-minded not long ago. This view stresses the role of social norms in
setting limits to inequality. According to this view, the New Deal had a more
profound impact on American society than even its most ardent admirers have
suggested: it imposed norms of relative equality in pay that persisted for more
than 30 years, creating the broadly middle-class society we came to take for
granted. But those norms began to unravel in the 1970's and have done so at an
accelerating pace.
Exhibit A for
this view is the story of executive compensation. In the 1960's, America's great
corporations behaved more like socialist republics than like cutthroat
capitalist enterprises, and top executives behaved more like public-spirited
bureaucrats than like captains of industry. I'm not exaggerating. Consider the
description of executive behavior offered by John Kenneth Galbraith in his 1967
book, ''The New Industrial State'': ''Management does not go out ruthlessly to
reward itself -- a sound management is expected to exercise restraint.''
Managerial self-dealing was a thing of the past: ''With the power of decision
goes opportunity for making money. . . . Were everyone to seek to do so . . .
the corporation would be a chaos of competitive avarice. But these are not the
sort of thing that a good company man does; a remarkably effective code bans
such behavior. Group decision-making insures, moreover, that almost everyone's
actions and even thoughts are known to others. This acts to enforce the code
and, more than incidentally, a high standard of personal honesty as well.''
Thirty-five years
on, a cover article in Fortune is titled ''You Bought. They Sold.'' ''All over
corporate America,'' reads the blurb, ''top execs were cashing in stocks even as
their companies were tanking. Who was left holding the bag? You.'' As I said,
we've become a different country.
Let's leave
actual malfeasance on one side for a moment, and ask how the relatively modest
salaries of top executives 30 years ago became the gigantic pay packages of
today. There are two main stories, both of which emphasize changing norms rather
than pure economics. The more optimistic story draws an analogy between the
explosion of C.E.O. pay and the explosion of baseball salaries with the
introduction of free agency. According to this story, highly paid C.E.O.'s
really are worth it, because having the right man in that job makes a huge
difference. The more pessimistic view -- which I find more plausible -- is that
competition for talent is a minor factor. Yes, a great executive can make a big
difference -- but those huge pay packages have been going as often as not to
executives whose performance is mediocre at best. The key reason executives are
paid so much now is that they appoint the members of the corporate board that
determines their compensation and control many of the perks that board members
count on. So it's not the invisible hand of the market that leads to those
monumental executive incomes; it's the invisible handshake in the boardroom.
But then why
weren't executives paid lavishly 30 years ago? Again, it's a matter of corporate
culture. For a generation after World War II, fear of outrage kept executive
salaries in check. Now the outrage is gone. That is, the explosion of executive
pay represents a social change rather than the purely economic forces of supply
and demand. We should think of it not as a market trend like the rising value of
waterfront property, but as something more like the sexual revolution of the
1960's -- a relaxation of old strictures, a new permissiveness, but in this case
the permissiveness is financial rather than sexual. Sure enough, John Kenneth
Galbraith described the honest executive of 1967 as being one who ''eschews the
lovely, available and even naked woman by whom he is intimately surrounded.'' By
the end of the 1990's, the executive motto might as well have been ''If it feels
good, do it.''
How did this
change in corporate culture happen? Economists and management theorists are only
beginning to explore that question, but it's easy to suggest a few factors. One
was the changing structure of financial markets. In his new book, ''Searching
for a Corporate Savior,'' Rakesh Khurana of Harvard Business School suggests
that during the 1980's and 1990's, ''managerial capitalism'' -- the world of the
man in the gray flannel suit -- was replaced by ''investor capitalism.''
Institutional investors weren't willing to let a C.E.O. choose his own successor
from inside the corporation; they wanted heroic leaders, often outsiders, and
were willing to pay immense sums to get them. The subtitle of Khurana's book, by
the way, is ''The Irrational Quest for Charismatic C.E.O.'s.''
But fashionable
management theorists didn't think it was irrational. Since the 1980's there has
been ever more emphasis on the importance of ''leadership'' -- meaning personal,
charismatic leadership. When Lee Iacocca of Chrysler became a business celebrity
in the early 1980's, he was practically alone: Khurana reports that in 1980 only
one issue of Business Week featured a C.E.O. on its cover. By 1999 the number
was up to 19. And once it was considered normal, even necessary, for a C.E.O. to
be famous, it also became easier to make him rich.
Economists also
did their bit to legitimize previously unthinkable levels of executive pay.
During the 1980's and 1990's a torrent of academic papers -- popularized in
business magazines and incorporated into consultants' recommendations -- argued
that Gordon Gekko was right: greed is good; greed works. In order to get the
best performance out of executives, these papers argued, it was necessary to
align their interests with those of stockholders. And the way to do that was
with large grants of stock or stock options.
It's hard to
escape the suspicion that these new intellectual justifications for soaring
executive pay were as much effect as cause. I'm not suggesting that management
theorists and economists were personally corrupt. It would have been a subtle,
unconscious process: the ideas that were taken up by business schools, that led
to nice speaking and consulting fees, tended to be the ones that ratified an
existing trend, and thereby gave it legitimacy.
What economists
like Piketty and Saez are now suggesting is that the story of executive
compensation is representative of a broader story. Much more than economists and
free-market advocates like to imagine, wages -- particularly at the top -- are
determined by social norms. What happened during the 1930's and 1940's was that
new norms of equality were established, largely through the political process.
What happened in the 1980's and 1990's was that those norms unraveled, replaced
by an ethos of ''anything goes.'' And a result was an explosion of income at the
top of the scale.
IV. The Price of Inequality
It was one of
those revealing moments. Responding to an e-mail message from a Canadian viewer,
Robert Novak of ''Crossfire'' delivered a little speech: ''Marg, like most
Canadians, you're ill informed and wrong. The U.S. has the longest standard of
living -- longest life expectancy of any country in the world, including Canada.
That's the truth.''
But it was Novak
who had his facts wrong. Canadians can expect to live about two years longer
than Americans. In fact, life expectancy in the U.S. is well below that in
Canada, Japan and every major nation in Western Europe. On average, we can
expect lives a bit shorter than those of Greeks, a bit longer than those of
Portuguese. Male life expectancy is lower in the U.S. than it is in Costa Rica.
Still, you can
understand why Novak assumed that we were No. 1. After all, we really are the
richest major nation, with real G.D.P. per capita about 20 percent higher than
Canada's. And it has been an article of faith in this country that a rising tide
lifts all boats. Doesn't our high and rising national wealth translate into a
high standard of living -- including good medical care -- for all Americans?
Well, no.
Although America has higher per capita income than other advanced countries, it
turns out that that's mainly because our rich are much richer. And here's a
radical thought: if the rich get more, that leaves less for everyone else.
That statement --
which is simply a matter of arithmetic -- is guaranteed to bring accusations of
''class warfare.'' If the accuser gets more specific, he'll probably offer two
reasons that it's foolish to make a fuss over the high incomes of a few people
at the top of the income distribution. First, he'll tell you that what the elite
get may look like a lot of money, but it's still a small share of the total --
that is, when all is said and done the rich aren't getting that big a piece of
the pie. Second, he'll tell you that trying to do anything to reduce incomes at
the top will hurt, not help, people further down the distribution, because
attempts to redistribute income damage incentives.
These arguments
for lack of concern are plausible. And they were entirely correct, once upon a
time -- namely, back when we had a middle-class society. But there's a lot less
truth to them now.
First, the share
of the rich in total income is no longer trivial. These days 1 percent of
families receive about 16 percent of total pretax income, and have about 14
percent of after-tax income. That share has roughly doubled over the past 30
years, and is now about as large as the share of the bottom 40 percent of the
population. That's a big shift of income to the top; as a matter of pure
arithmetic, it must mean that the incomes of less well off families grew
considerably more slowly than average income. And they did. Adjusting for
inflation, average family income -- total income divided by the number of
families -- grew 28 percent from 1979 to 1997. But median family income -- the
income of a family in the middle of the distribution, a better indicator of how
typical American families are doing -- grew only 10 percent. And the incomes of
the bottom fifth of families actually fell slightly.
Let me belabor
this point for a bit. We pride ourselves, with considerable justification, on
our record of economic growth. But over the last few decades it's remarkable how
little of that growth has trickled down to ordinary families. Median family
income has risen only about 0.5 percent per year -- and as far as we can tell
from somewhat unreliable data, just about all of that increase was due to wives
working longer hours, with little or no gain in real wages. Furthermore, numbers
about income don't reflect the growing riskiness of life for ordinary workers.
In the days when General Motors was known in-house as Generous Motors, many
workers felt that they had considerable job security -- the company wouldn't
fire them except in extremis. Many had contracts that guaranteed health
insurance, even if they were laid off; they had pension benefits that did not
depend on the stock market. Now mass firings from long-established companies are
commonplace; losing your job means losing your insurance; and as millions of
people have been learning, a 401(k) plan is no guarantee of a comfortable
retirement.
Still, many
people will say that while the U.S. economic system may generate a lot of
inequality, it also generates much higher incomes than any alternative, so that
everyone is better off. That was the moral Business Week tried to convey in its
recent special issue with ''25 Ideas for a Changing World.'' One of those ideas
was ''the rich get richer, and that's O.K.'' High incomes at the top, the
conventional wisdom declares, are the result of a free-market system that
provides huge incentives for performance. And the system delivers that
performance, which means that wealth at the top doesn't come at the expense of
the rest of us.
A skeptic might
point out that the explosion in executive compensation seems at best loosely
related to actual performance. Jack Welch was one of the 10 highest-paid
executives in the United States in 2000, and you could argue that he earned it.
But did Dennis Kozlowski of Tyco, or Gerald Levin of Time Warner, who were also
in the top 10? A skeptic might also point out that even during the economic boom
of the late 1990's, U.S. productivity growth was no better than it was during
the great postwar expansion, which corresponds to the era when America was truly
middle class and C.E.O.'s were modestly paid technocrats.
But can we
produce any direct evidence about the effects of inequality? We can't rerun our
own history and ask what would have happened if the social norms of middle-class
America had continued to limit incomes at the top, and if government policy had
leaned against rising inequality instead of reinforcing it, which is what
actually happened. But we can compare ourselves with other advanced countries.
And the results are somewhat surprising.
Many Americans
assume that because we are the richest country in the world, with real G.D.P.
per capita higher than that of other major advanced countries, Americans must be
better off across the board -- that it's not just our rich who are richer than
their counterparts abroad, but that the typical American family is much better
off than the typical family elsewhere, and that even our poor are well off by
foreign standards.
But it's not
true. Let me use the example of Sweden, that great conservative bete noire.
A few months ago
the conservative cyberpundit Glenn Reynolds made a splash when he pointed out
that Sweden's G.D.P. per capita is roughly comparable with that of Mississippi
-- see, those foolish believers in the welfare state have impoverished
themselves! Presumably he assumed that this means that the typical Swede is as
poor as the typical resident of Mississippi, and therefore much worse off than
the typical American.
But life
expectancy in Sweden is about three years higher than that of the U.S. Infant
mortality is half the U.S. level, and less than a third the rate in Mississippi.
Functional illiteracy is much less common than in the U.S.
How is this
possible? One answer is that G.D.P. per capita is in some ways a misleading
measure. Swedes take longer vacations than Americans, so they work fewer hours
per year. That's a choice, not a failure of economic performance. Real G.D.P.
per hour worked is 16 percent lower than in the United States, which makes
Swedish productivity about the same as Canada's.
But the main
point is that though Sweden may have lower average income than the United
States, that's mainly because our rich are so much richer. The median Swedish
family has a standard of living roughly comparable with that of the median U.S.
family: wages are if anything higher in Sweden, and a higher tax burden is
offset by public provision of health care and generally better public services.
And as you move further down the income distribution, Swedish living standards
are way ahead of those in the U.S. Swedish families with children that are at
the 10th percentile -- poorer than 90 percent of the population -- have incomes
60 percent higher than their U.S. counterparts. And very few people in Sweden
experience the deep poverty that is all too common in the United States. One
measure: in 1994 only 6 percent of Swedes lived on less than $11 per day,
compared with 14 percent in the U.S.
The moral of this
comparison is that even if you think that America's high levels of inequality
are the price of our high level of national income, it's not at all clear that
this price is worth paying. The reason conservatives engage in bouts of
Sweden-bashing is that they want to convince us that there is no tradeoff
between economic efficiency and equity -- that if you try to take from the rich
and give to the poor, you actually make everyone worse off. But the comparison
between the U.S. and other advanced countries doesn't support this conclusion at
all. Yes, we are the richest major nation. But because so much of our national
income is concentrated in relatively few hands, large numbers of Americans are
worse off economically than their counterparts in other advanced countries. And
we might even offer a challenge from the other side: inequality in the United
States has arguably reached levels where it is counterproductive. That is, you
can make a case that our society would be richer if its richest members didn't
get quite so much.
I could make this
argument on historical grounds. The most impressive economic growth in U.S.
history coincided with the middle-class interregnum, the post-World War II
generation, when incomes were most evenly distributed. But let's focus on a
specific case, the extraordinary pay packages of today's top executives. Are
these good for the economy?
Until recently it
was almost unchallenged conventional wisdom that, whatever else you might say,
the new imperial C.E.O.'s had delivered results that dwarfed the expense of
their compensation. But now that the stock bubble has burst, it has become
increasingly clear that there was a price to those big pay packages, after all.
In fact, the price paid by shareholders and society at large may have been many
times larger than the amount actually paid to the executives.
It's easy to get
boggled by the details of corporate scandal -- insider loans, stock options,
special-purpose entities, mark-to-market, round-tripping. But there's a simple
reason that the details are so complicated. All of these schemes were designed
to benefit corporate insiders -- to inflate the pay of the C.E.O. and his inner
circle. That is, they were all about the ''chaos of competitive avarice'' that,
according to John Kenneth Galbraith, had been ruled out in the corporation of
the 1960's. But while all restraint has vanished within the American
corporation, the outside world -- including stockholders -- is still prudish,
and open looting by executives is still not acceptable. So the looting has to be
camouflaged, taking place through complicated schemes that can be rationalized
to outsiders as clever corporate strategies.
Economists who
study crime tell us that crime is inefficient -- that is, the costs of crime to
the economy are much larger than the amount stolen. Crime, and the fear of
crime, divert resources away from productive uses: criminals spend their time
stealing rather than producing, and potential victims spend time and money
trying to protect their property. Also, the things people do to avoid becoming
victims -- like avoiding dangerous districts -- have a cost even if they succeed
in averting an actual crime.
The same holds
true of corporate malfeasance, whether or not it actually involves breaking the
law. Executives who devote their time to creating innovative ways to divert
shareholder money into their own pockets probably aren't running the real
business very well (think Enron, WorldCom, Tyco, Global Crossing, Adelphia . . .
). Investments chosen because they create the illusion of profitability while
insiders cash in their stock options are a waste of scarce resources. And if the
supply of funds from lenders and shareholders dries up because of a lack of
trust, the economy as a whole suffers. Just ask Indonesia.
The argument for
a system in which some people get very rich has always been that the lure of
wealth provides powerful incentives. But the question is, incentives to do what?
As we learn more about what has actually been going on in corporate America,
it's becoming less and less clear whether those incentives have actually made
executives work on behalf of the rest of us.
V. Inequality and Politics
In September the
Senate debated a proposed measure that would impose a one-time capital gains tax
on Americans who renounce their citizenship in order to avoid paying U.S. taxes.
Senator Phil Gramm was not pleased, declaring that the proposal was ''right out
of Nazi Germany.'' Pretty strong language, but no stronger than the metaphor
Daniel Mitchell of the Heritage Foundation used, in an op-ed article in The
Washington Times, to describe a bill designed to prevent corporations from
rechartering abroad for tax purposes: Mitchell described this legislation as the
''Dred Scott tax bill,'' referring to the infamous 1857 Supreme Court ruling
that required free states to return escaped slaves.
Twenty years ago,
would a prominent senator have likened those who want wealthy people to pay
taxes to Nazis? Would a member of a think tank with close ties to the
administration have drawn a parallel between corporate taxation and slavery? I
don't think so. The remarks by Gramm and Mitchell, while stronger than usual,
were indicators of two huge changes in American politics. One is the growing
polarization of our politics -- our politicians are less and less inclined to
offer even the appearance of moderation. The other is the growing tendency of
policy and policy makers to cater to the interests of the wealthy. And I mean
the wealthy, not the merely well-off: only someone with a net worth of at least
several million dollars is likely to find it worthwhile to become a tax exile.
You don't need a
political scientist to tell you that modern American politics is bitterly
polarized. But wasn't it always thus? No, it wasn't. From World War II until the
1970's -- the same era during which income inequality was historically low --
political partisanship was much more muted than it is today. That's not just a
subjective assessment. My Princeton political science colleagues Nolan McCarty
and Howard Rosenthal, together with Keith Poole at the University of Houston,
have done a statistical analysis showing that the voting behavior of a
congressman is much better predicted by his party affiliation today than it was
25 years ago. In fact, the division between the parties is sharper now than it
has been since the 1920's.
What are the
parties divided about? The answer is simple: economics. McCarty, Rosenthal and
Poole write that ''voting in Congress is highly ideological -- one-dimensional
left/right, liberal versus conservative.'' It may sound simplistic to describe
Democrats as the party that wants to tax the rich and help the poor, and
Republicans as the party that wants to keep taxes and social spending as low as
possible. And during the era of middle-class America that would indeed have been
simplistic: politics wasn't defined by economic issues. But that was a different
country; as McCarty, Rosenthal and Poole put it, ''If income and wealth are
distributed in a fairly equitable way, little is to be gained for politicians to
organize politics around nonexistent conflicts.'' Now the conflicts are real,
and our politics is organized around them. In other words, the growing
inequality of our incomes probably lies behind the growing divisiveness of our
politics.
But the politics
of rich and poor hasn't played out the way you might think. Since the incomes of
America's wealthy have soared while ordinary families have seen at best small
gains, you might have expected politicians to seek votes by proposing to soak
the rich. In fact, however, the polarization of politics has occurred because
the Republicans have moved to the right, not because the Democrats have moved to
the left. And actual economic policy has moved steadily in favor of the wealthy.
The major tax cuts of the past 25 years, the Reagan cuts in the 1980's and the
recent Bush cuts, were both heavily tilted toward the very well off. (Despite
obfuscations, it remains true that more than half the Bush tax cut will
eventually go to the top 1 percent of families.) The major tax increase over
that period, the increase in payroll taxes in the 1980's, fell most heavily on
working-class families.
The most
remarkable example of how politics has shifted in favor of the wealthy -- an
example that helps us understand why economic policy has reinforced, not
countered, the movement toward greater inequality -- is the drive to repeal the
estate tax. The estate tax is, overwhelmingly, a tax on the wealthy. In 1999,
only the top 2 percent of estates paid any tax at all, and half the estate tax
was paid by only 3,300 estates, 0.16 percent of the total, with a minimum value
of $5 million and an average value of $17 million. A quarter of the tax was paid
by just 467 estates worth more than $20 million. Tales of family farms and
businesses broken up to pay the estate tax are basically rural legends; hardly
any real examples have been found, despite diligent searching.
You might have
thought that a tax that falls on so few people yet yields a significant amount
of revenue would be politically popular; you certainly wouldn't expect
widespread opposition. Moreover, there has long been an argument that the estate
tax promotes democratic values, precisely because it limits the ability of the
wealthy to form dynasties. So why has there been a powerful political drive to
repeal the estate tax, and why was such a repeal a centerpiece of the Bush tax
cut?
There is an
economic argument for repealing the estate tax, but it's hard to believe that
many people take it seriously. More significant for members of Congress, surely,
is the question of who would benefit from repeal: while those who will actually
benefit from estate tax repeal are few in number, they have a lot of money and
control even more (corporate C.E.O.'s can now count on leaving taxable estates
behind). That is, they are the sort of people who command the attention of
politicians in search of campaign funds.
But it's not just
about campaign contributions: much of the general public has been convinced that
the estate tax is a bad thing. If you try talking about the tax to a group of
moderately prosperous retirees, you get some interesting reactions. They refer
to it as the ''death tax''; many of them believe that their estates will face
punitive taxation, even though most of them will pay little or nothing; they are
convinced that small businesses and family farms bear the brunt of the tax.
These
misconceptions don't arise by accident. They have, instead, been deliberately
promoted. For example, a Heritage Foundation document titled ''Time to Repeal
Federal Death Taxes: The Nightmare of the American Dream'' emphasizes stories
that rarely, if ever, happen in real life: ''Small-business owners, particularly
minority owners, suffer anxious moments wondering whether the businesses they
hope to hand down to their children will be destroyed by the death tax bill, . .
. Women whose children are grown struggle to find ways to re-enter the work
force without upsetting the family's estate tax avoidance plan.'' And who
finances the Heritage Foundation? Why, foundations created by wealthy families,
of course.
The point is that
it is no accident that strongly conservative views, views that militate against
taxes on the rich, have spread even as the rich get richer compared with the
rest of us: in addition to directly buying influence, money can be used to shape
public perceptions. The liberal group People for the American Way's report on
how conservative foundations have deployed vast sums to support think tanks,
friendly media and other institutions that promote right-wing causes is titled
''Buying a Movement.''
Not to put too
fine a point on it: as the rich get richer, they can buy a lot of things besides
goods and services. Money buys political influence; used cleverly, it also buys
intellectual influence. A result is that growing income disparities in the
United States, far from leading to demands to soak the rich, have been
accompanied by a growing movement to let them keep more of their earnings and to
pass their wealth on to their children.
This obviously
raises the possibility of a self-reinforcing process. As the gap between the
rich and the rest of the population grows, economic policy increasingly caters
to the interests of the elite, while public services for the population at large
-- above all, public education -- are starved of resources. As policy
increasingly favors the interests of the rich and neglects the interests of the
general population, income disparities grow even wider.
VI. Plutocracy?
In 1924, the
mansions of Long Island's North Shore were still in their full glory, as was the
political power of the class that owned them. When Gov. Al Smith of New York
proposed building a system of parks on Long Island, the mansion owners were
bitterly opposed. One baron -- Horace Havemeyer, the ''sultan of sugar'' --
warned that North Shore towns would be ''overrun with rabble from the city.''
''Rabble?'' Smith said. ''That's me you're talking about.'' In the end New
Yorkers got their parks, but it was close: the interests of a few hundred
wealthy families nearly prevailed over those of New York City's middle class.
America in the
1920's wasn't a feudal society. But it was a nation in which vast privilege --
often inherited privilege -- stood in contrast to vast misery. It was also a
nation in which the government, more often than not, served the interests of the
privileged and ignored the aspirations of ordinary people.
Those days are
past -- or are they? Income inequality in America has now returned to the levels
of the 1920's. Inherited wealth doesn't yet play a big part in our society, but
given time -- and the repeal of the estate tax -- we will grow ourselves a
hereditary elite just as set apart from the concerns of ordinary Americans as
old Horace Havemeyer. And the new elite, like the old, will have enormous
political power.
Kevin Phillips
concludes his book ''Wealth and Democracy'' with a grim warning: ''Either
democracy must be renewed, with politics brought back to life, or wealth is
likely to cement a new and less democratic regime -- plutocracy by some other
name.'' It's a pretty extreme line, but we live in extreme times. Even if the
forms of democracy remain, they may become meaningless. It's all too easy to see
how we may become a country in which the big rewards are reserved for people
with the right connections; in which ordinary people see little hope of
advancement; in which political involvement seems pointless, because in the end
the interests of the elite always get served.
Am I being too
pessimistic? Even my liberal friends tell me not to worry, that our system has
great resilience, that the center will hold. I hope they're right, but they may
be looking in the rearview mirror. Our optimism about America, our belief that
in the end our nation always finds its way, comes from the past -- a past in
which we were a middle-class society. But that was another country.
Originally
published in the New York Times, 10.20.02
Sources
for the NYT Magazine Article
SYNOPSIS:
For those who are interested, here
are the data sources for the Oct. 20th piece.
For part 2, "The New Gilded Age":
The standard source for data on growing inequality is the Census "historical
income tables" home page .
These tables show a sharp rise in inequality. However, for reasons explained by
a CBO
study , these data understate incomes at the top - which is where the
biggest action is. The CBO estimates for 1979-1997 can be found here . A
more readable summary of the
main conclusions of the CBO report is offered by the Center on Budget and Policy
Priorities. These data tell us that the gains of the top 1 percent have been
much, much bigger than those of the next 4 percent, let alone the top quintile;
this suggests that there are even bigger gains as you move to the really rich,
the top 0.1 percent or even less. Sure enough, a paper by Piketty and Saez ,
forthcoming in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, uses income tax data
to track the incomes of the very rich since 1913, and finds immense gains at the
top. (An amazing observation: the share of percentiles 90-95 has not risen
significantly over the last 30 years; all of the gain in the top decile
is in the top 5 percent, 80 percent of it in the top 1 percent. So much for
90-10 comparisons as a measure of inequality trends.) This paper is also a
convenient source of data on executive compensation. A full set of tables and
figures, some of which aren't in the final version, is available in worksheet
format .
For part 4, "The price of
inequality":A good source for international comparisons of life expectancy,
infant mortality, poverty, and other social indicators is the appendix to the
UN's Human Development Report . For more focused comparisons of the U.S.
with other advanced countries, the work of economists associated with the
Luxembourg Income Study is extremely helpful; a nice set of notes by Smeeding provides comparisons of absolute income at
the 10th and 90th percentile.
For part 5, "Inequality and
politics", I have found the work of McCarty, Poole, and Rosenthal eye-opening.
The general source for this material is Poole's home page at Houston. (It's a
funny factoid, which does not at all reflect on Poole, that he is the Kenneth L.
Lay Professor of Political Science.) To understand how he and his colleagues
quantify political positions, and why this is useful, read this methodological note . For an
overview of the remarkable polarization of U.S. politics in recent decades, read
this set of notes
(click on "the Polarization of US Politics").. For an analysis of the
relationship between income polarization and political polarization, see this
paper .
For the facts about the estate tax,
see this report from the Center on Budget and Policy
Priorities.
Originally published on the Official
Paul Krugman Site, 10.18.02