Solutions for Why Medical Bills Are Killing Us
How outrageous
pricing and egregious profits are destroying our health care
By Steven Brill
Apr 04, 2013
For more, visit TIME Health https://time.com/time-health/
We should tighten
antitrust laws related to hospitals to keep them from becoming so dominant in a
region that insurance companies are helpless in negotiating prices with them.
The hospitals' continuing consolidation of both lab work and doctors' practices
is one reason that trying to cut the deficit by simply lowering the fees
Medicare and Medicaid pay to hospitals will not work. It will only cause the
hospitals to shift the costs to non-Medicare patients in order to maintain
profits — which they will be able to do because of their increasing leverage in
their markets over insurers. Insurance premiums will therefore go up — which in
turn will drive the deficit back up, because the subsidies on insurance
premiums that Obamacare will soon offer to those who cannot afford them will
have to go up.
Similarly, we should tax
hospital profits at 75% and have a tax surcharge on all nondoctor hospital
salaries that exceed, say, $750,000. Why are high profits at hospitals regarded
as a given that we have to work around? Why shouldn't those who are profiting
the most from a market whose costs are victimizing everyone else chip in to
help? If we recouped 75% of all hospital profits (from nonprofit as well as
for-profit institutions), that would save over $80 billion a year before
counting what we would save on tests that hospitals might not perform if their
profit incentives were shaved.
To be sure, this too
seems unlikely to happen. Hospitals may be the most politically powerful
institution in any congressional district. They're usually admired as their
community's most important charitable institution, and their influential
stakeholders run the gamut from equipment makers to drug companies to doctors
to thousands of rank-and-file employees. Then again, if every community paid
more attention to those administrator salaries, to those nonprofits' profit
margins and to charges like $77 for gauze pads, perhaps the political balance
would shift.
We should outlaw the
chargemaster. Everyone involved, except a patient who gets a bill based on one
(or worse, gets sued on the basis of one), shrugs off chargemasters as a
fiction. So why not require that they be rewritten to reflect a process that
considers actual and thoroughly transparent costs? After all, hospitals are
supposed to be government-sanctioned institutions accountable to the public.
Hospitals love the chargemaster because it gives them a big number to put in
front of rich uninsured patients (typically from outside the U.S.) or, as is
more likely, to attach to lawsuits or give to bill collectors, establishing a
place from which they can negotiate settlements. It's also a great place from
which to start negotiations with insurance companies, which also love the
chargemaster because they can then make their customers feel good when they get
an Explanation of Benefits that shows the terrific discounts their insurance
company won for them.
But for patients, the
chargemasters are both the real and the metaphoric essence of the broken
market. They are anything but irrelevant. They're the source of the poison
coursing through the health care ecosystem.
We should amend patent
laws so that makers of wonder drugs would be limited in how they can exploit
the monopoly our patent laws give them. Or we could simply set price limits or
profit-margin caps on these drugs. Why are the drug profit margins treated as
another given that we have to work around to get out of the $750 billion annual
overspend, rather than a problem to be solved?
Just bringing these
overall profits down to those of the software industry would save billions of
dollars. Reducing drugmakers' prices to what they get in other developed
countries would save over $90 billion a year. It could save Medicare — meaning
the taxpayers — more than $25 billion a year, or $250 billion over 10 years.
Depending on whether that $250 billion is compared with the Republican or
Democratic deficit-cutting proposals, that's a third or a half of the Medicare
cuts now being talked about.
Similarly, we should
tighten what Medicare pays for CT or MRI tests a lot more and even cap what
insurance companies can pay for them. This is a huge contributor to our massive
overspending on outpatient costs. And we should cap profits on lab tests done
in-house by hospitals or doctors.
Finally, we should
embarrass Democrats into stopping their fight against medical-malpractice
reform and instead provide safe-harbor defenses for doctors so they don't have
to order a CT scan whenever, as one hospital administrator put it, someone in
the emergency room says the word head. Trial lawyers who make their bread and
butter from civil suits have been the Democrats' biggest financial backer for
decades. Republicans are right when they argue that tort reform is overdue.
Eliminating the rationale or excuse for all the extra doctor exams, lab tests
and use of CT scans and MRIs could cut tens of billions of dollars a year while
drastically cutting what hospitals and doctors spend on malpractice insurance
and pass along to patients.
Other options are more
tongue in cheek, though they illustrate the absurdity of the hole we have
fallen into. We could limit administrator salaries at hospitals to five or six
times what the lowest-paid licensed physician gets for caring for patients
there. That might take care of the self-fulfilling peer dynamic that Gunn of
Sloan-Kettering cited when he explained, "We all use the same compensation
consultants." Then again, it might unleash a wave of salary increases for
junior doctors.
Or we could require drug
companies to include a prominent, plain-English notice of the gross profit
margin on the packaging of each drug, as well as the salary of the parent
company's CEO. The same would have to be posted on the company's website. If
nothing else, it would be a good test of embarrassment thresholds.
None of these
suggestions will come as a revelation to the policy experts who put together
Obamacare or to those before them who pushed health care reform for decades.
They know what the core problem is — lopsided pricing and outsize profits in a
market that doesn't work. Yet there is little in Obamacare that addresses that
core issue or jeopardizes the paydays of those thriving in that marketplace. In
fact, by bringing so many new customers into that market by mandating that they
get health insurance and then providing taxpayer support to pay their insurance
premiums, Obamacare enriches them. That, of course, is why the bill was able to
get through Congress.
Obamacare does some good
work around the edges of the core problem. It restricts abusive hospital-bill
collecting. It forces insurers to provide explanations of their policies in
plain English. It requires a more rigorous appeal process conducted by
independent entities when insurance coverage is denied. These are all positive
changes, as is putting the insurance umbrella over tens of millions more
Americans — a historic breakthrough. But none of it is a path to bending the
health care cost curve. Indeed, while Obamacare's promotion of statewide
insurance exchanges may help distribute health-insurance policies to
individuals now frozen out of the market, those exchanges could raise costs,
not lower them. With hospitals consolidating by buying doctors' practices and
competing hospitals, their leverage over insurance companies is increasing.
That's a trend that will only be accelerated if there are more insurance
companies with less market share competing in a new exchange market trying to
negotiate with a dominant hospital and its doctors. Similarly, higher insurance
premiums — much of them paid by taxpayers through Obamacare's subsidies for
those who can't afford insurance but now must buy it — will certainly be the
result of three of Obamacare's best provisions: the prohibitions on exclusions
for pre-existing conditions, the restrictions on co-pays for preventive care
and the end of annual or lifetime payout caps.
Put simply, with
Obamacare we've changed the rules related to who pays for what, but we haven't
done much to change the prices we pay.
When you follow the
money, you see the choices we've made, knowingly or unknowingly.
Over the past few
decades, we've enriched the labs, drug companies, medical device makers,
hospital administrators and purveyors of CT scans, MRIs, canes and wheelchairs.
Meanwhile, we've squeezed the doctors who don't own their own clinics, don't
work as drug or device consultants or don't otherwise game a system that is so
gameable. And of course, we've squeezed everyone outside the system who gets
stuck with the bills.
We've created a secure,
prosperous island in an economy that is suffering under the weight of the
riches those on the island extract.
And we've allowed those
on the island and their lobbyists and allies to control the debate, diverting
us from what Gerard Anderson, a health care economist at the Johns Hopkins
Bloomberg School of Public Health, says is the obvious and only issue:
"All the prices are too damn high."